Article body

Matt Ridley’s How Innovation Works is destined to be a classic of popular social science; well written, argued and researched. This book should be on the bookshelf of every business school professor. For those who research business history and entrepreneurship, this book is a blessing as it provides well-explained theory with excellent examples. I would strongly recommend this book as a text for an undergraduate class. Likewise, this book is a rebuttal for those who dismiss modern capitalism and entrepreneurship. Simply put, I am writing this review on a laptop that did not exist 50 years ago. I ordered the book online, a method that did not exist until 25 years ago. These are just two examples of many (Ridley has scores of examples) demonstrating how humanity has emerged from a grim past.

Ridley’s work is a correction to the theory that great individuals make history or the “great man theory.’ As he shows innovation is often the result of an evolutionary process, with numerous false steps, competing strategies, and is random in nature. Thomas Edison may have invented the first practical lightbulb—but there were 21 competitors hot on his heels. Although inventors play a key role in that, they combine these various elements, nevertheless, the process is random and cannot be directed through government programs. Although government can be a partner (something Ridley undervalues). Furthermore, mere invention is not enough, rather as Ridley demonstrates, new discoveries must establish they are “sufficiently practical, affordable, reliable, and ubiquitous to be worth using.” Sometimes, as in case of “gorilla glass,” used in the modern cellphone, the invention could occur well before it becomes important or useful.

Likewise, Ridley is highly skeptical of the ability of governments to create innovation. Although Ridley does not cite Hayek; he clearly understands the complexity of information that no one person, especially a dictator, can harness the information needed to innovation. Rather only when we have a free society, where information can be changed, can innovation truly occur. Likewise, Ridley also demonstrates that governments can ban items for no reason—except either to help politically connected groups or out of ignorance. Margarine and coffee were considered products of the devil due to the impact they had on existing producers. Ridley notes; “entrepreneurial spirit often goes into protecting existing interests, rather than the creation of new products.”

Ridley is a Conservative member of the House of Lords. Therefore, people will believe his answer is ideologically charged. Ridley does have an ideological viewpoint; however, his viewpoint is based upon on excellent theorizing as well as historical examples. For example, Ridley cite the case of the competition between the R100, made by Vickers, and R101, made by the government. The one made by the private corporation worked; the government one did not. He has a libertarian perspective, arguing that patents on technology may not be needed. As an example, he cites the impact of the internet and music. Napster made music more available; artists now had to create more music. Likewise, Ridley is also highly critical of big business, noting the failure of IBM to further develop products. His arguments for the malfunction of both big business and big government in innovation is that the rules of their game: conformity; are different then the rules of innovation: contrarianism.

As could with any book, some criticism is warranted. Firstly, innovation and invention are not as well defined and distinct as they need to be. This may be partly because Ridley’s work covers both aspects of science and social science without delineating the difference. For Ridley, it is clear that the “great man argument” is not a recipe for innovation to occur. Ridley cites as an example the discovery of the double helix, which, while Watson and Crick discovered it, there were several scientists hot on their tail, including Linus Pauling. While this is true in this case, nevertheless, in social science, ideas are constantly rediscovered. For example, Charles Babbage discovered much of what would become of scientific management well before Frederick Winslow Taylor. However, Babbage lacked the drive, “monomania”, and networking that Taylor possessed. This slowed the development of modern management by about 60 years.

Secondly, Ridley underplay the element of time. Six months between multiple discoveries appears short, but it could make all the difference. Imagine what would have happened if Hitler created the atomic bomb, before America did. Likewise, the social aspect of society plays a key role. Some societies, like the United States, place a high emphasis and legitimacy upon innovation. Others, such as Ridley’s Britain, have, at times, downplayed innovation. I share Ridley’s dubious belief that space exploration led to the development of LCD screens. I disagree with Ridley that space exploration was an art, rather than a benefit. Although LCD screens would have been invented regardless, the fact that they had the legitimacy of a successful program, probably aided in their adoption.

One last criticism: Ridley is correct that naysayers can be damaging to the acceptance of innovation. However, innovation can be damaging. The 20th century saw widespread increases in the quality of life as we escaped the Malthusian trap. However, the 20th century was also, as Robert Conquest referred to it, “the ravaged century.” Millions murdered by the weapons of modern perverted science. While activists who attack genetically modified organisms are Luddites, nevertheless, they could eventually be correct when we start genetically modifying humans. Likewise, sometimes when jobs and industries are destroyed, there is upheaval, something Joseph Schumpeter understood.

However, this is a book that is a corrective to naysayers. The greatest resource of all is knowledge. Knowledge is the endogenous, non-rival factor, that individuals can use, without depleting it. That knowledge is dispersed and cannot be controlled by a single factor or guiding intelligence. Rather than conformity and control, two factors that drive modern elites support, innovation is created by dispersed knowledge. If we accept this, our future may be limitless. However, it violates much of the orthodoxy pervading in politics and big business.